Ten Advantages of a Federal Constitution

Ten Advantages of a Federal Constitution

 

Professor Geoffrey de Q. Walker

http://www.samuelgriffith.org.au/papers/html/volume10/v10chap11.htm

Introduction: The New Age of Federalism

Worldwide interest in federalism is greater today than at any other time in human history.1 The old attitude of benign contempt towards the federal political structure has been replaced by a growing conviction that it enables a nation to have the best of both worlds, those of shared rule and self-rule, co-ordinated national government and diversity, creative experimentation and liberty. “Political leaders, leading intellectuals and even some journalists increasingly speak of federalism as a healthy, liberating and positive form of organization”,2 writes a leading Canadian authority. With the move of South Africa towards a federal structure, all the world’s geographically large countries are now federations with the exception of China, and even that country has become a de facto federation by delegating more and more autonomy to the provinces, as well as allowing Hong Kong semi-independent status as an autonomous region.

The same trend is apparent in countries that are not so physically large. There was scarcely any question in the minds of East Germans that, on their release from captivity, they would rejoin the nation as the five federal states (Lander) that had been suppressed by Hitler and later by the Communists. Belgium, which had previously lived under a unitary constitution modelled on Britain’s, became a federation in 1993.

The few remaining highly centralized democratic nation states, such as the United Kingdom, France, Spain, Sri Lanka and Italy have all faced major crises of secession or devolution. Spain has had to relax its grip on the provinces as a result of pressures in the Basque country and Catalonia. Northern Italy has a vigorous separatist movement. France has established regional councils with legislative power, though what the people really want is the return of nos belles provinces. The United Kingdom has been slowly disintegrating for over a century, with the sometimes violent struggle for Home Rule gaining strength in the 1880s, the independence of Ireland in 1921 followed by Scottish and Welsh nationalism, and by civil war in Northern Ireland. The current government is now taking grudging steps towards a semi-federal structure. Sri Lanka’s British – designed unitary structure has had catastrophic results that might have been avoided if the Tamil regions had possessed some degree of self-rule under a federal arrangement.

Whereas in 1939 a Harold Laski could declare that “the epoch of federalism is over”, it would be truer to say, as the new millennium approaches, that unitary government has proved unstable and that we are in fact entering the “Age of Federalism”.3

One reason for this favourable reassessment is the ending of the great confrontation between liberal democracy and tyranny that lasted from 1914 to the fall of the Berlin Wall in 1989. Democracy’s success in that conflict removed one of the main justifications for centralized government, the need to maintain an economic structure that could be mobilized. While the collapse of the Soviet Union and its empire has undermined the appeal of all authoritarian, centralizing ideologies, the spread of human rights values has called in question all traditional forms of elite governance, and created increasing pressure for genuine citizen self-government. The general wariness towards utopian ideologies has also helped in the sense that federalism is not an ideology. It is a pragmatic and prudential compromise, intended to meet both the common and the diverse preferences of people by combining shared rule on some matters with self-rule on others.4

Economic change has been a factor too. An increasingly global economy has unleashed centrifugal economic and political forces that have weakened the traditional nation state in some respects and strengthened both international and local pressures. The spread of free markets has stimulated socio-economic developments that favour federalism : the emphasis on autonomous contractual relationships, recognition of the non-centralized nature of a market economy, consumer rights consciousness, and the thriving of markets on diversity rather than uniformity.

Related to this are advances in technology that are causing the optimum size of efficient businesses to shrink, and models of industrial organization with decentralized and flattened structures involving non-centralized interactive networks.5 A further reason is the observable prosperity, stability and longevity of the main democratic federations : the United States, Canada, Australia and Switzerland. Together with New Zealand and Sweden, they are the only countries to have passed more or less intact through the furnace of the twentieth century.6 (The United Kingdom fails to qualify because of Ireland’s secession.) But while Sweden and New Zealand are unitary states, not federations, they account even today for only 12 million people between them. It should also be noted that no federation has ever changed to a unitary system except as the result of a totalitarian takeover.

Throughout the world conferences, seminars and special purpose organizations are now being put together to study and debate federalism as a liberal political ideal. In Australia, valuable work on this concept has been done by a number of scholars, and by bodies such as the Centre for Independent Studies, the Australian Institute for Public Policy and, of course, The Samuel Griffith Society.

Within the Australian political-intellectual clerisy, however, attitudes to federalism range from viewing it as a necessary evil to, as one recent work puts it, “waiting for an appropriate time in which to abolish our spent State legislatures”.7 There are several reasons for this dismissive, even hostile view of our constitutional structure. One is the lingering influence among intellectuals and the media of the ideologies of bureaucratic centralism which, though discredited in the real world, are still able to evoke powerful myths in the minds of those who do not place a high value on the lessons of experience. The influence of British academic writings has in the past also been a source of centralist prejudice, as the British intellectual establishment has been anti-federalist since at least the days of A.V. Dicey. Another reason is a kind of pseudo-pragmatism expressed in casual one-line assertions about the costs of a federal division of power. This attitude not only fails to consider the costs of the alternative but, more importantly for present purposes, it takes no account of the positive benefits of the federal model.

To some extent these attitudes are understandable. The pattern of constitutional interpretation followed by the High Court over most of this century has consistently tended to favour the expansion of Commonwealth power at the expense of the States. This has made it increasingly difficult for the States to perform their proper role, so that the advantages of constitutionally decentralized government are more and more difficult to identify and evaluate. This factor was highlighted when the recent High Court decision invalidating state retail taxes8 provoked a renewed chorus of calls for the abolition of the States.

Again, federal and State governments have been able to create a kind of political cartel by the increasing use of uniform “national” legislation and by heavy reliance on special-purpose grants. These developments have the effect, and probably the purpose, of denying to the people the opportunity to make comparisons between different models of legislation, taxation and spending.

To the extent that the one-sided nature of the public debate on federalism stems from the lack of information about, and recent experience of, the proper working of a federal system, it may be useful to draw together and articulate in one place the main points on the other side of the argument.

We should start by defining the term “federation”. Decades of debate have not produced a universally accepted formula, but the list of characteristics put forward by Professor Watts of Queen’s University, Canada, will serve:

  • two orders of government, each acting directly on its citizens, a formal distribution of legislative and executive authority, and allocation of revenue resources between the two orders of government, including some areas of autonomy for each order;
  • provision for the representation of regional views within the federal policy-making institutions;
  • a written supreme Constitution not unilaterally amendable and requiring the consent of all or a majority of the constituent units;
  • an umpire (courts or referendums) to rule on disputes between governments;
  • processes to facilitate intergovernmental relations for those areas where responsibilities are shared or overlap.9

A key element in this definition is the requirement of a written Constitution. Other forms of governmental decentralization which exist only as a matter of central government policy, and can be restricted or abolished at any time, such as the regional assemblies of France, cannot be regarded as federal systems. At least in theory, Australia comes within Professor Watts’s definition. What, then, are the advantages of such a system?

Advantages of a federal system:

1. The right of choice and exit

When we think of political rights in a democracy, those that first come to mind are usually the right to vote and the right of political free speech. While they are indeed crucial, an equally important and more long-standing right is the liberty to decide whether or not to live under a particular system of government, the right to “vote with one’s feet” by moving to a different State or country.

That this is a political right is obvious from the events leading up to the fall of the Soviet Union. The Communist governments were the only regimes in history ever to suppress that right almost completely. The Soviet authorities well knew that if their subjects should ever seize or be granted that right, the Communist system would instantly collapse. And that, of course, is what happened.

The citizen in a liberal unitary state who is dissatisfied with the national government may of course leave and go to live in another country. But these days it is becoming harder to obtain a permanent resident visa for the kind of country to which one might wish to emigrate. Globalism notwithstanding, immigration is increasingly unpopular with voters the world over.

In a federation, however (including a quasi-federal association such as the European Union), there is complete freedom to migrate to other states. A federal structure allows people to compare different political systems operating in the same country and to give effect to those comparisons by voting with their feet. This process of comparison, choice and exit has occurred on a massive scale in Australia, especially during the eighties and early nineties. During those years Australians moved in huge numbers from the then heavily-governed southern States to the then wide open spaces of Queensland.10

The freedom to leave has been recognized as a political right longer than perhaps any other attribute of citizenship. Plato’s dramatized account of the last days of Socrates has the philosopher restating the principle in context:

“[A]ny Athenian, on attaining to manhood and seeing for himself the political organization of the State and its Laws, is permitted, if he is not satisfied with [them], to take his property and go away wherever he likes”.11

In the seventeenth century, Thomas Hobbes wrote of the consent of the governed as embodied in the willingness of the citizen to live under a particular government and respect its laws. That tacit consent gave legitimacy to a ruler even before the advent of modern democracy12 — indeed, it was the only form of political legitimacy available at that time.

A federal Constitution therefore operates as a check on the ability of State and Territory governments to exploit or oppress their citizens. This function did not appear in the first of the modern federal Constitutions (that of the United States) as a matter of conscious design — it is merely a happy by-product of the system. None of the early commentaries discuss the value of federalism as a check on state power. Nevertheless, it is clearly an inseparable consequence of any federal structure.13

According to Professor Richard Epstein of the University of Chicago, the freedom of individual choice among governments in a federation is one of the most effective of the usual safeguards against governmental excesses, the others being the full separation of powers and a legally enforceable Bill of Rights. The special merit of the right of exit is that it is a self-help remedy, simple, cheap and effective.14

Some other American commentators argue that it is the most effective of the three safeguards.15 Judge Robert Bork, in support of this view, points out that the division of power between federal government and States is the only constitutional protection of liberty that is neutral, in the sense that you can choose to move to the State that protects the particular freedoms you cherish most, regardless of whether they are specifically protected by the Constitution or find favour with judges.16 At the very least, one must agree with Gordon Tullock’s conclusion that: “The addition of voting with your feet to voting with a ballot is a significant improvement”.17

So when centralists give federalism the disparaging label “States’ rights”, they are obscuring the fact that it is above all the people’s right to vote with their feet that is protected by the constitutional division of sovereignty in a federal system. (The States themselves — if one means by that their governments — have, on the contrary, shown an increasing willingness to surrender their rights to the Commonwealth.)18

This beneficial feature of federalism has two limitations, however. One is that it gives existing residents no protection for assets that cannot be moved, such as land or licences.19 The New South Wales Parliament exploited this limitation spectacularly in 1981, when it legislated to confiscate all privately-owned coal deposits in the State without giving the owners a right to compensation.20

The effectiveness of exit as a remedy is also limited by the number of States. The fewer States there are, the fewer the choices, and the greater the opportunities for governments to collude on taxes, spending priorities and other areas of law or policy that are important to the citizen. The small number of States in Australia, as compared with ten Provinces in Canada, twenty-three Swiss cantons and fifty American States, makes collusion more likely and more effective.21 This is analogous to the problem of the small number of firms in some Australian industries in the early days of economic competition policy under the Trade Practices Act. As under that Act, therefore, the relatively small number of choices makes it all the more important to preserve and expand such potential for competition as the number of competitors allows.

2. The possibility of experiment

The British constitutional scholar James (Viscount) Bryce in 1888 published a monumental treatise on the United States that became the standard reference manual at Australia’s federal conventions.22 The fact that it is known to have been assiduously studied and constantly cited by the delegates makes it a valuable guide to the understanding and the intentions of Australia’s Founders. In his appraisal of the American system Bryce identified among the main benefits of federalism “the opportunities it affords for trying easily and safely experiments which ought to be tried in legislation and administration”.23

This is the same point as Justice Brandeis was making in his famous statement that:

“To stay experimentation in things social and economic is a grave responsibility. Denial of the right to experiment may be fraught with dangerous consequences to the Nation. It is one of the happy incidents of the federal system that a single courageous State may, if its citizens choose, serve as a laboratory; and try novel social and economic experiments without risk to the rest of the country”.24

In other words, the autonomy of the States allows the nearest thing to a controlled experiment that is available in the sphere of law-making and government policy. Being closer to the workface, State governments are in a better position than the national government to assess the costs as well as the benefits of particular policies as revealed in this way. Not only that, but the possibility of competition among States creates incentives for each one to experiment with ways of providing the combination of public goods that will maximize the welfare of a majority of its voters, and perhaps attract people and other resources from other States.25

All this is particularly important in times of rapid social change. As Karl Mannheim pointed out, “every major phase of social change constitutes a choice between alternatives”,26 and there is no way a legislator can be certain in advance which policy will work best. For example, de facto relationships have attracted legislative attention recently because society has no experience in dealing with them on the present scale. Which is the best policy: the interventionist, paternalist approach of the New South Wales De Facto Relationships Act 1984, or the common law libertarianism of Queensland and Western Australia? The only way to be certain is to observe what happens in practice under each approach. The evidence produced by comparing the results of different policies in different States may force a modification of the approach, provided that the legislature is open to rational persuasion.

Besides making experiment and comparison possible, a federal system also makes it harder for legislatures to avoid or dismiss evidence that undermines the approach they have taken. The results of experience in one’s own country are less easily ignored than evidence from foreign lands.

That is another reason why ideologues tend to be hostile to federalism. Hardly a week passes without some activist group lamenting the “inconsistent” (the term being misused to mean merely “different”)27 approaches taken by State laws to current social or economic issues, and calling for uniform “national” legislation to deal with the problem. Behind these calls for uniformity lies a desire to impose the activists’ preferred approach on the whole Commonwealth, precisely so that evidence about the effectiveness of other approaches in Australian conditions will not become available. Unless experimentation can be suppressed, the activists cannot isolate their theory from confrontation with contrary evidence.28

The Family Law Act 1975 is an example of a law that has been insulated from feedback in this way. Seldom has an Australian law been as consistently controversial, both as regards its substance and its administration, as Lionel Murphy’s federal legislation in this vital field.29 A good case can be made for uniform divorce laws, rather than the separate State laws that existed before 1959,30 but in this case uniformity has been purchased at a cost that many Australians still regard as too heavy. If evidence produced by alternative contemporary approaches had existed, some salutary adjustments might have been made.31

Not only may suppressing the possibility of experiment be too high a price to pay for uniformity, but the uniformity itself may be an illusion. The federal Evidence Act1995, intended to be re-enacted by all the States, was promoted with the claim that uniform legislation was needed to put an end to the “differences in the laws of evidence capable of affecting the outcome of litigation according to the State or Territory which is the venue of the trial”.32 The Act certainly does away with some legal differences, but in most cases it does so by granting the trial judge a discretion whether to admit the evidence or not.

As Justice Einstein of the New South Wales Supreme Court has pointed out, the exercise of these discretions is not normally reviewable on appeal. Consquently, the result of the legislation is a substantial extension of the powers of individual trial judges in matters of admissibility.33 So instead of eight different State or Territory laws capable of affecting the outcome of a case, we now have, in effect, as many different evidence “laws” as there are trial judges. Besides adding greatly to the uncertainty of the law, this represents a major transfer of discretionary power from the private sphere to the public sector, in this case the judicial arm of government. Since to date only New South Wales has adopted the Act, it remains open to the other States to experiment with reformed evidence laws (uniform or not) that do not suffer from those defects.

Neither uniformity nor diversity is an absolute value in itself. Sometimes the gains from nationwide uniformity will outweigh the benefits of independent experimentation. This will usually be the case in areas where there is long experience to draw on, such as defence arrangements, the official language, railway gauges, currency, bills of exchange, weights and measures and sale of goods. But experimentation has special advantages in dealing with the new problems presented in a rapidly changing society, or in developing new solutions when the old ones are no longer working.

3. Accommodating regional preferences and diversity

Unity in diversity. The decentralization of power under a federal constitution gives a nation the flexibility to accommodate variations in economic bases, social tastes and attitudes. These characteristics correlate significantly with geography, and State laws in a federation can be adapted to local conditions in a way that is difficult to achieve through a national government. By these means overall satisfaction can be maximized,34 and the winner-take-all problem inherent in raw democracy alleviated. Professor McConnell illustrates the point with this example:

“[A]ssume that there are only two States, with equal populations of 100 each. Assume further that 70 per cent of State A, and only 40 per cent of State B, wish to outlaw smoking in public buildings. The others are opposed. If the decision is made on a national basis by a majority rule, 110 people will be pleased, and 90 displeased. If a separate decision is made by majorities in each State, 130 will be pleased, and only 70 displeased. The level of satisfaction will be still greater if some smokers in State A decide to move to State B, and some anti-smokers in State B decide to move to State A”.35

Government overall thus becomes more in harmony with the people’s wishes, as Professor Sharman explains:

“[F]ederalism enhances the range of governmental solutions to any given problem and consequently makes the system as a whole more responsive to the preferences of groups and individuals”.36

Paradoxically, perhaps, a structure that provides an outlet for minority views strengthens overall national unity. Without the guarantee of regional self-government, Western Australia, at least, would not have joined the Commonwealth. The State has a long-standing secession movement that has revived in recent years. If that guarantee were by some means abolished, the West might secede, perhaps taking one or two other States with it. Wayne Goss, when Premier of Queensland, was making essentially this point when he warned that abolishing the States, even de facto, could fracture the unity of the nation.37 Federalism thus has an important role, as Lord Bryce observed, in keeping the peace and preventing national fragmentation.38 It is far from impossible that if the British had adopted a federal structure, as many reformers in the last century urged,39 the Irish might have preferred to stay in the United Kingdom (or the “Federal Kingdom” as it might then have been) and a century of strife might have been avoided.

Cultural differences in Australia. Though the fact is often overlooked in Canberra and Sydney, there are attitudinal and cultural differences between the Australian States. These differences are sometimes quite marked, and not only in Queensland, despite the tendency of some southern commentators to view the State as a pathological aberration. “It should be recognized”, writes former Chief Justice Green of Tasmania, “that although relatively speaking the Australian population as a whole is fairly homogeneous, each State and Territory has different laws, values, history, economic profiles, electoral and parliamentary systems and court systems”.40

Some commentators see regional socio-cultural diversity as the only possible explanation and justification of federalism. This leads to the assertion that the regional differentiation of social characteristics in Australia is not sufficiently pronounced to warrant a federal structure. The borders between the States are purely arbitrary, it is argued, so the States lack a genuine social basis.41 Those propositions are unfounded, for reasons succinctly expressed by Professor Sharman:

“To begin with, a sense of political community can exist quite independently of social differences between communities. Geographical contiguity, social interaction and a sharing of common problems all tend to create a feeling of community, whether it is a street, a neighbourhood or a State. The chestnut about the arbitrary nature of State boundaries is not only wrong as a geographical observation for many State borders — deserts, Bass Strait and the Murray River are hardly arbitrary lines — but fundamentally misconceives the nature and consequences of boundaries. Drawing political borders on a featureless plain is an arbitrary act, but once drawn, those lines rapidly acquire social reality”.42

To Sharman’s list of the natural boundaries between the States one could add the Queensland border ranges, which mark the beginning of the eastern tropical and sub-tropical zones, and the factor of sheer distance between the urban settled areas, a feature perhaps more marked in Australia than in any other country. Despite the wonders of modern communication, if people are really to understand and empathize with one another, they still need to meet and talk face to face. So it could never be said here, as Lord Bryce said of America, that “The states are not areas set off by nature”, with only California having genuine natural frontiers, the Pacific and the Sierra Nevada.43 Yet in America the States have undoubtedly become real political communities in the way described by Sharman, including the arbitrarily-drawn “quadrilateral” States west of the Mississippi.

Less can be better. The argument that Australia is too homogeneous to be a federation also runs into the problem that federalism plainly works best when socio-cultural differences are not too great or too territorially delineated. Multi-ethnic federations are among the hardest to sustain.44 The United States has had no serious secessionist movement since 1865 because, although it is a land of unbelievable diversity, the areas occupied by competing minorities do not correspond closely with political boundaries. For example, there is no State, or group of States, that is overwhelmingly black, or American Indian, or Jewish, or Catholic or Asian.

The same is true of language, ethnic and religious differences in Switzerland, to a lesser extent.45 The Swiss Constitution, however, has the added advantage that its citizen-initiated referendum system makes it virtually impossible for politicians to engage in fear-based manipulation of regional or other differences.

Contrast Canada, where most of the French-speaking population is concentrated in Quebec, which in turn is overwhelmingly francophone. The results are obvious. Similar tensions caused Singapore, which is almost entirely Chinese, to secede from the Malaysian federation.

In this light, Australia’s relative socio-cultural homogeneity is an argument for, not against, a federal structure.

Isolating discord. Federalism’s tolerance for diversity has the further advantage of preventing the national government from being forced to take sides on matters of purely regional concern. This is consistent with the axiom of modern management science that problems should so far as possible be dealt with where they arise. As Lord Bryce put it:

“…..the looser structure of a federal government and the scope it gives for diversities of legislation in different parts of a country may avert sources of discord, or prevent local discord from growing into a contest of national magnitude”.46

For example, the Northern Territory’s voluntary euthanasia legislation became a national political issue because, as a Territory enactment, it could be overridden by a Commonwealth Act.47 Had the issue arisen in a State, there might still have been a nationwide debate, but the federal government would not have been directly involved.

Subsidiarity. In Europe this principle is called “subsidiarity”, and it is now enshrined as a fundamental guiding principle in the European Union treaties.48 Article 3b (2) of the European Community treaty defines subsidiarity as meaning that the Community shall take action “if and only in so far as the objectives of the proposed action cannot be sufficiently achieved by the Member States and can therefore, by reason of the scale or effect of the proposed action, be better achieved by the Community”. Obviously, much will depend on how this piece of treatyspeak is applied in practice, but the principle’s adoption is credited with saving the 1991 Maastricht agreement.49 Public misgivings over the centralizing ambitions of the French president of the Commission at the time, Jacques Delors, might otherwise have blocked any further progress towards European integration.

4. Participation in government and the countering of elitism

A federation is inherently more democratic than a unitary system because there are more levels of government for public opinion to affect.50 The great historian Lord Acton went further, saying that in any country of significant size, popular government could only be preserved through a federal structure. Otherwise the result would be elite rule by a single city:

“For true republicanism is the principle of self-government in the whole and in all the parts. In an extensive country, it can prevail only by the union of several independent communities in a single confederacy, as in Greece,51 in Switzerland, in the Netherlands, and in America, so that a large republic not founded on the federal principle must result in the government of a single city, like Rome and Paris; or, in other words, a great democracy must either sacrifice self-government to unity, or preserve it by federalism”.52

De Tocqueville was making the same point more broadly when he wrote that democracy works best when it proceeds from the bottom up, not from the top down, with the central state growing out of a myriad of associations and local governments.53 Decentralized government makes people a little more like active participants than passive recipients; it produces men and women who are citizens rather than subjects, and gives government a greater degree of legitimacy.

The fall and rise of political elitism. This more deeply democratic aspect of federalism is especially important at a time when elitist theories of government, albeit clothed in democratic rhetoric, are once again in vogue. The struggle between the idea of government by the people and government by an elite is as old as the Western political tradition itself. In fact, political philosophy was founded on this controversy: Plato’s The Republic was largely his criticism of democracy in the form in which it was practised at Athens. In its latest manifestation, the conflict between elitism and democracy explains modern politics more satisfactorily than the traditional division between left and right.54

Elitism has been dominant throughout most of history. The democracy that exists today in countries influenced by the Western tradition is only two centuries old, a legacy of the French and American revolutions. When united with the English traditions of liberty and the rule of law, democracy has produced not only an unprecedented measure of individual freedom but also a huge and unsurpassed increase in the material well-being of the masses.

Despite democracy’s success, elitism has never conceded defeat. Throughout the nineteenth Century, critics assailed the belief that the common man could govern as being contrary to experience and an absurdity. One after another, new theories were advanced to justify rule by a select few, on technocratic grounds, on the basis of some romantic “superman” mystique, or by reason of a supposed historical inevitability. In the twentieth Century those theories brought forth the twin poisoned fruit of Communism and Hitlerian national socialism.

The defeat of those two monstrosities through the heroic efforts and sacrifice of ordinary men and women has not brought democracy final victory. For the 1960s saw the sprouting of a new hybrid of the old Platonic plant that has now grown to a position of dominance.

This is a model of government that lies somewhere between the traditional poles of democracy and elitism, a model in which the power of an enlightened minority would help democracy to survive and progress. The several variations of this model have come to be known as the “theories of democratic elitism”. The late Christopher Lasch deplored this “paltry view of democracy that has come to prevail in our time” as reduced to nothing more than a system for recruiting leaders, replacing the Jeffersonian ideal community of self-reliant, self-governing citizens with a mechanism for merely ensuring the circulation of elites.55

The new wave of elitism has gained added momentum from the trend towards globalization. The growth of a global consciousness is no doubt a good thing, but the other side of the coin is that it has opened the way for unrepresentative bodies such as the United Nations and its agencies to implement an elitist agenda under the pretext of promulgating “international norms”.56 International relations circles have acknowledged this problem and given it the label “democratic deficit”, but no steps other than cosmetic measures have been taken to overcome it.

Free speech for all, or the few? The new elitism, and the characteristics of the groups it has brought to power, have been explored by Lasch, Thomas Sowell, Jeffrey Bell, Robert Nisbet and others,57 so there is no need to detail them here. One striking example of how these theories have worked in Australia should be noted, however, if only to show their ominous practical consequences.

From the 1970s onwards, elitist politicians have repeatedly attempted to instal an elitist version of the doctrine of free speech, under which the government would decide which political issues would be admitted to the public forum, and by whom they would be debated. In August – September, 1975 the Whitlam federal government proposed a scheme whereby newspapers would be granted (or deprived of) a licence to publish by a special government body on the basis of whether or not they were meeting the needs of the “community”.58 The wave of public fear generated by this blatant attempt at political censorship was a major factor leading to the 1975 constitutional crisis, though it is never mentioned in media accounts of those events.

The next attempt was the Political Broadcasts and Political Disclosures Act 1991, promoted by Senator Nick Bolkus, which prohibited all political advertising (paid or unpaid) on radio or television in the period leading up to an election. Blocks of free air time were to be allocated to approved parties by a government-appointed panel. The Act was overturned by the High Court in one of its best-ever decisions,59 but Senator Bolkus and his academic supporters remain on the offensive. Recently the Senator has advanced a new proposal based, not on direct prohibition as in 1991, but on a de facto takeover of political debate by nationally funded elite bodies. “[T]alk is cheap,” he writes. “Real freedom of speech is about resourcing durable institutions within society that can present alternative views, critique government policy, and review government decisions”.60

No doubt, if given the opportunity, Senator Bolkus will seek to put his revised vision into effect. If he succeeds, his view of public political debate as “cheap”, ill-informed and unenlightened, could be self-realizing. It was Christopher Lasch, following William James, who perceived that our search for reliable information is itself guided by the questions that arise during argument about a given course of action. It is only through the test of debate that we come to understand what we know and what we still need to learn.61 Exclude the people from political debate and you deny them the incentive to become well informed.

With democracy’s victory obviously only half complete, we must continue to defend all available supports for popular government. As elites will resist any new outlets for public opinion,62 it is all the more important to protect the inherently more open and democratic political texture afforded by our federal system.

Creative controversy. In one sense, as Campbell Sharman points out, federalism’s more open texture will produce political conflict, “but it does this only as a reflection of the increased opportunity for individual and group access to the governmental process — such conflict is clearly highly desirable”. Federalism, he explains:

“…..simply makes visible and public differences which would occur under any system of government. It is nonsense to think that problems would disappear if Australia became a unitary state, and there would be few who would argue that the politics of bureaucratic intrigue is preferable to the open cut and thrust of competitive partisan politics in the variety of forums provided by a federal structure”.63

The interrelation of government bodies, then, is as much of a problem in unitary states as in federations. Gordon Tullock observes that relations between Arizona and New Mexico are much less unfriendly than those between the federal State Department and the CIA.64

On the basis of democratic values alone, therefore, we should not allow the elitists to talk us out of federalism. Its greater opportunities for popular participation are a major political end in themselves. They foster a sense of responsibility and self-reliance.65 They lead to better-informed public debate. And, as Lord Acton said, they “provide against the servility which flourishes under the shadow of a single authority”.66

5. The federal division of powers protects liberty

Barrier of our liberty. We saw above how a federal structure protects citizens from oppression or exploitation on the part of State governments by allowing them the right of exit, to vote with their feet by moving to another State. But the diffusion of law-making power under federalism is also a shield against an arbitrary central government. When Thomas Jefferson declared that “the true barriers of our liberty in this country are our State governments”,67 he meant that the Constitution’s “vertical” separation of legislative powers between Congress and the States performed a function similar to the “horizontal” separation of powers between legislative, executive and judicial arms of government. Lord Bryce likewise affirmed that “federalism prevents the rise of a despotic central government, absorbing other powers, and menacing the private liberties of the citizen”.68

The imperfections of human nature meant that no-one could be trusted with total power; in Lord Acton’s words, all power corrupts, but absolute power corrupts absolutely. Power therefore had to be dispersed. Good government, as Montesquieu had observed, also required that people should be unafraid, and concentrations of power give rise to apprehensions that they will be used tyrannically. By dividing sovereignty, the federal division of powers reduces both the risk of authoritarianism and the apprehension of it. “Liberty provokes diversity,” Acton remarked, “and diversity preserves liberty by supplying the means of organization”.69 The States therefore also help to preserve freedom, because they can rally citizens to the cause of freedom, helping to overcome the organizational problems that otherwise might cause national usurpations to go unchallenged by the “silent majority” of citizens.70

The States help to preserve judicial independence and impartiality as well. The existence of independent State court structures prevents a national government from filling all the courts in the land with judges believed to be its supporters. Even the late Geoffrey Sawer, an eminent constitutional lawyer but definitely no federalist, had to concede the value of a federal structure as a safeguard of liberty.71

That this aspect of the federal compact has not attracted much attention or comment in Australia is probably a function of history. Newcomers from Europe have often remarked that Australians are too complacent about their freedom because they have never had to fight for it. That is not quite true, at least as regards external threats; from 1941 to 1945 Australians were defending their liberty in the most direct way possible. But the perception is generally correct in relation to internal threats. After the Australian colonies in the 1850s “erected what were for the time advanced democratic political institutions”,72 democratic progress followed a course that was smoother than anywhere else in the world. There was no turbulent formative period comparable to the American revolutionary era, which seems permanently to have sensitized Americans to infringements of their freedom. Australians received no inoculation of that kind. That they should have come to take their freedom for granted was to some extent understandable.

Recent assaults. But a succession of federal government attacks on civil and political rights over recent decades make such nonchalance now quite unjustifiable. First there have been the already noted attempts to restrict political debate in the media. Then Malcolm Fraser’s retrospective tax legislation, which broke the constitutional convention against ex post facto law-making, and led in due course to the widely-criticized practice of “legislation by ministerial fiat”.73 Proliferating quasi-judicial tribunals took politically sensitive areas of law away from the ordinary courts so as to deprive accused persons of due process, subjecting them to rulings by tribunals whose members were appointed precisely because they were known not to be impartial.74

One of the most dramatic challenges to liberty was the Australia Card Bill 1985, which would have required citizens to carry a government number recorded on an identity card. Among its many other consequences, this legislation would have reversed the constitutional presumption that it is for the government to justify its actions to the people, not the other way around.75 Further, the whole concept of responsible government born of the 1688 English revolution, under which the executive government is responsible to Parliament, has been made a legal fiction by modern party discipline. It was finally buried in 1993 when Paul Keating announced that ministers, including the Prime Minister, would no longer be available to answer questions in the House, but would attend on a roster basis This move stemmed from Mr Keating’s earlier-expressed view that Question Time “is a courtesy extended to the House by the executive branch of government”, and did not reflect any right that Parliament might have to demand an account from the political Executive.76 The Executive’s counter-revolution against the 1688 settlement was thus largely complete.

Then we have seen the manipulation of the media through the government-funded National Media Liaison Service and the use of threats and intimidation against individual journalists.77 The Kirribilli Agreement, in some ways Australian democracy’s lowest point, showed that government leaders could with impunity conspire to deceive the electorate about the fundamental matter of who was to lead the government after the election.78 Finally, there is extensive evidence of systematic ballot-rigging, on a scale sufficient to have altered the outcome of at least one recent federal election.79 The Joint Standing Committee on Electoral matters, on the basis of that evidence, recommended some obvious changes to the electoral laws, such as requiring proof of identity for enrolment and voting, but the government Bill embodying those reforms has been blocked by the Opposition in the Senate.80

Especially arresting is the fact that all these attacks on liberty have occurred, not during a war or similar calamity that might have excused or explained some of them, but in a period of peace and general prosperity. A country with a recent record like that has no reason to assume that its freedom is secure. In particular, it has much to fear from any further concentration of government power.

Recent experience shows, therefore, that contemporary Australia needs the federal division of power, not just in the weakened form left by successive pro-centralist decisions of the High Court, but in something like its intended sharpness, as a check on the arrogance of central power. Federal politicians have shown themselves no more immune to human failings than their State counterparts, but more dangerous because of their monopoly powers in key areas, the support of a huge, pro-centralist bureaucracy, and the fiscal stranglehold that the High Court has bestowed on them.

Even in its present battered condition, Australian federalism has shown its value as a safeguard of liberty. For example, Premiers and other State political leaders helped to organize the opposition to the 1991 political advertising ban. The New South Wales government was a plaintiff in the successful High Court challenge to the legislation, the most important milestone in the progress of Australian democracy since Federation.

An end in itself. In a properly working federation, a national government seeking to implement a uniform policy in an area where it has no constitutional power must learn to proceed by negotiating and seeking consensus, not by diktat, bribery or menaces.81 It must learn to evaluate the costs as well as the benefits, to consider the evidence against its theories as well as in favour.82 Government by consensus can not only be more efficient, it can also be an end in itself, as Professor Sharman explains:

“[I]t should be noted that national governments have a strong preference for imposed solutions rather than negotiated ones. While it may be frustrating for a national government to acquire the consent of six other governments for some uniform scheme of legislation, this says nothing about either the desirability of the finished product or about the virtues of compromise and accommodation as inherently desirable characteristics of the governmental process”.83

6. Better supervision of government

Decentralized governments make better decisions than centralized ones, for reasons additional to the spur of competition provided by the citizen’s right of choice and exit.84 There are two main reasons for this.

Lower monitoring costs. Lord Bryce found that “the growth of order and civilization” in the United States had been aided by the fact that State governments were more closely watched by the people than Congress could have been.85 For the same reason, “It deserves to be noticed”, he continued, “that, in granting self-government to all those of her colonies whose population is of English race, England has practically adopted the same plan as the United States”.86 Leaving aside the Victorian view of the “English race”, the point is a good one, as the rationale behind power devolution to the then British colonies is often overlooked. It contrasts with the French pattern of colonial self-government, which was, and still is, to permit the colonies to elect members of the National Assembly in Paris, while administering the colonies simply as overseas departments of France.

The closer supervision of State governments is a function of lower monitoring costs. There are fewer programs and employees, and the amounts of tax revenue involved are smaller. Citizens can exercise more effective control over government officials when everything is on a smaller scale.87 Large governments encourage wasteful lobbying by interest groups engaged in what economists call “rent-seeking”, the pursuit of special group benefits or privileges. Rent-seeking is easier in large than in small governments, because it is harder for ordinary citizens to see who is preying on them. The lower information costs at the lower echelons make it easier to spot the deals made with interest groups at the State government level.88 Further, the more liable to abuse the powers involved, the more important it is that they should be decentralized, according to Professor Calabresi:

“[I]t often makes sense to lodge dangerous and intrusive police powers over crime and over controversial social issues in the States, where government officials may be monitored more easily by the citzenry”.89

The general observation about the freer flow and readier absorption of information about State government is borne out by the Australian scene. Most of the content of the major Australian newspapers relates to State and local matters. The national dailies have much smaller circulations than their State-based rivals, and successive attempts by the Australian Broadcasting Corporation to adopt a national format for its news and current affairs programs have failed.

In that case, then, how to account for the financial disasters of the Victorian, South Australian and Western Australian governments in the late 1980s? Here, it seems, the central problem was not federal structure but media behaviour. Information about the looming disasters existed but, largely because of the political leanings of reporters, editors and producers, it was not passed on to the public. Paul Keating as Treasurer attacked Melbourne’s The Age for having covered up the Victorian government’s evolving financial debacles,90 and others have made similar charges about the ABC and the press in the three affected States. But the same kind of thing was also happening in Canberra. The difference was that the federal government was not content to rely on political predispositions, but resorted to threats and reprisals against media organizations and individual journalists.91 (More on this later).

Coping with size. The greater ease of supervising State government is a function of the broader proposition that a physically large country without a federal system is ungovernable. Jefferson was emphatic that the United States, which in his day was only a fraction of its present size, was “too large to have all its affairs directed by a single government”.92 In our own time, even a centralist like Geoffrey Sawer had to admit that in Australia, geographic factors make a good deal of devolution of powers inevitable.93

Lord Bryce thought this factor of special importance in a new country:

“It permits an expansion whose extent, and whose rate and manner of progress, cannot be foreseen, to proceed with more variety of methods, more adaptation of laws and administration to the circumstances of each part of the territory, and altogether in a more natural and spontaneous way, than can be expected under a centralized government…..”

and the spirit of self-reliance among those who build up new communities is stimulated and respected.94 Federalism also relieved the national legislature of “a part of that large mass of functions that might otherwise prove too heavy for it”. The “great council of the nation” thus had more time to deliberate on those questions that most closely affected the whole country.95

A less obvious result of dividing a large country into States with some commonality of socio-cultural attitudes is given by Professor Calabresi. He argues that State governments may be able to enforce criminal laws and regulations of social mores less coercively than the national government, because of the lower costs and greater ease of monitoring citizen behaviour in a smaller jurisdiction than in a continent-sized commonwealth:

“The greater congruence of mores between citizens and representatives in State governments may in turn produce greater civic-mindedness and community spirit at the State level”.96

This might offset the decline of public spiritedness at the national level,97 which in Australia is linked with the palpable public antipathy towards Canberra (most notably in the outlying States) and the Commonwealth Parliament, especially in the days when the tone of debate was set by Mr Keating.

7. Stability

Stability is a cardinal virtue in government. Stable government enables individuals and groups to plan their activities with some confidence, and so makes innovation and lasting progress possible.

Political stability is much valued by ordinary people because they are the ones likely to suffer the most from sudden shocks or changes of direction in the government of the country. A stable polity is in that sense more democratic than an unstable one, other things being equal. This, as Carl Friedrich pointed out, is a function of the political prudence of the common man, who finds stability the best framework in which to think out matters of great weight in an environment shot through with political propaganda.98

Stability is obviously a high priority with the Australian people. This can be seen from their widespread practice of voting for different parties in each of the two Houses of Parliament, thereby denying the government a free hand in passing whatever legislation it likes. Based on the voters’ profound distrust of the career politician, this practice reduces the destabilizing potential of transient majorities in the lower house.

Professor Brian Galligan supports this assessment with his observation that the traditional literature on Australian politics has exaggerated the radical character of the national ethos, while at the same time overlooking the stabilizing effect of the Constitution.99

What is the source of this stability? The federal compact, Professor Galligan continues, deals in an ingenious way with the problem of the multiplicity of competing answers and the lack of obvious solutions by setting government institutions against one another:

“The shape of the nation is as much the product of the interaction and clash of competing ideas and institutions as it is of any intentional order or national consensus. That is particularly and deliberately so for a federal system of government that breaks up national majorities and sets government institutions against one another”.100

And the people prefer it that way, as their votes in constitutional referendums show.

The result is that while, in a federation, sweeping reforms are more difficult, they are also less likely to be necessary. Successive federal governments have encountered more frustrations in their efforts to restructure the economy than their counterparts in the United Kingdom and New Zealand, but the Australian economy was not in such dire need of restructuring. The nation’s federal system had effectively prevented earlier governments from matching the excesses of collectivism attained in pre-Thatcher Britain101 or the bureaucratic wilderness of “Muldoonery” in New Zealand. Opinion polls in those two countries show that most people consider the reforms made by the Thatcher and Lange governments to have been beneficial, but the process was a stressful and destabilizing one. In New Zealand it led to public pressures that resulted in substantial changes to the whole system of parliamentary representation.

The stability that federalism promotes also has a valuable flow-on effect in the political consciousness of the people, according to Lord Bryce. It strengthens “their sense of the value of stability and permanence in political arrangements. It trains them to habits of legality, as the law of the Twelve Tables trained the minds of the educated Romans”.102 In this way federalism tends to become a self-reinforcing system almost with a life of its own. 103

8. Fail-safe design

Besides acting as a brake on extreme or impetuous action by the national government, federalism cushions the nation as a whole from the full impact of government blunders or other reverses. Lord Bryce likened a federal nation to a ship built with watertight compartments:

“When a leak is sprung in one compartment, the cargo stowed there may be damaged, but the other compartments remain dry and keep the ship afloat”.104

Professor Watts uses the more modern fail-safe analogy:

“The redundancies within federations provide fail-safe mechanisms and safety valves enabling one sub-system within a federation to respond to needs when another fails to. In this sense, the very inefficiencies about which there are complaints may be the source of a longer-run basic effectiveness“.105

In this way federalism makes it harder for any one group of politicians to ruin the entire economy at once. The deadly mixture of corporate statism with public sector expansion on borrowed money that undid Victoria, South Australia and Western Australia in the 1980s was also the fashionable policy in Canberra at the time. It might well have been comprehensively extended to the whole country if the constitutional power to do so had existed. Had that happened, Australia might not be weathering the Asian economic storm as well as it is.

For the same reasons, damage control can bring results more quickly when the impact of an economic mistake or misfortune can be localized in this way. The three States that were devastated in the 1980s have now recovered from their tribulations. In their reconstruction processes they were able to borrow policies that had proved successful in other States: fiscal policy from Queensland, privatization and reform of government business enterprises from New South Wales, scaling back the public sector from Tasmania.106 Repairing the damage done by a policy error in an area where the Commonwealth has a monopoly, such as monetary policy, seems to take longer, however. The crippling inflation ignited by Treasurer Frank Crean’s 1973 federal Budget has only recently been brought under control, almost a generation later.

One should therefore not assume that a healthy national economy requires, or will even be assisted by, comprehensive macro-economic and micro-economic control from the centre. Economists increasingly take the view that the role of national governments is best confined to establishing general rules that set an overall framework for market processes (the economic order),107 and that centralized fiscal control creates a “fiscal illusion” by disguising the true cost of public services and making government look smaller than it is.108 In this way it perpetuates the “collectivist hand-out culture in public finance”.109

The economic columnist Padraic P McGuinness maintains that it is quite practicable to devolve tax and fiscal policy powers to the States, because under a unified currency it is not possible for one State to conduct an inflationary fiscal policy by running budget deficits for very long. There is no good reason, he writes, for Canberra to deny to States the possibility of divergent policies with respect to the overall level of revenue raising and spending. Most of the powers the Commonwealth exercises in relation to economic policy are not only unnecessary, but positively counter-productive:

“In fact, the need for central macro-economic policy is largely the product of over-regulation and mistaken micro-economic policies”.110

9. Competition and efficiency in government

Like all other human institutions, governments if given the chance will tend to behave like monopolists. In Australia it has taken firm constitutional constraints to prevent the federal government from restricting political broadcasts so as to abridge the public’s opportunities to compare political policies and personalities.111 A government that can restrict comparisons and prevent people from voting with their feet is in the position of a classic single-firm monopolist, and can be as inefficient and oppressive as it likes. The paradigm case is the former Soviet Union.

Government of the people, for the governors. Inefficiency in government usually takes either or both of two forms. One is a tendency to higher tax rates, which is obvious and easy to detect. The other, less obvious, has been identified and extensively described by the economists who have developed the “public choice” model of government that has achieved wide acceptance in recent years.

This model is based on the proposition that government agents (elected representatives and public servants) act from the same motives of rational self-interest as other people. It predicts that government programs will be administered so as to minimize the proportion of the program’s budget that is actually received by the intended beneficiaries, with the remainder — the surplus —being used to further the interests of the administrators. Those administering, for example, a program to pay money to the poor will minimize the revenues directed to the needy, and use the surplus to expand the administering bureaucracy, improve staff gradings and pay for overseas conference travel.112 The politicians in charge will use the surplus to acquire added powers of patronage through opportunities to appoint their supporters to boards, committees and specialist tribunals.

A government that enjoys monopoly power is able to generate such a surplus for discretionary use by officials and politicians.113 An often-cited illustration of this is Australia’s set of federal policies designed to benefit the Aboriginal people. The States also have Aboriginal assistance programs, but these have not attracted the same kind or degree of criticism, perhaps because a higher proportion of the funds are being used for their intended purpose.

Another example is Australia’s public university system. In the days when they were administered by the States, the universities were efficient bodies with the “flattened” management profile so admired today. A dean’s administrative duties seldom took as much as a day per week, and even vice-chancellors were part-time officials who spent much of their time on teaching and research. Commonwealth involvement consisted mainly of funding Commonwealth scholarships, which were available to any student who did better than average in the final school examinations. As a result, fully 70 per cent of students went through their tertiary education paying no fees at all.

The transformation began in 1974 when the Commonwealth assumed financial control over the universities, relying on the conditional grants power in s.96 of the Constitution. Access to the proceeds of the Commonwealth’s monopoly over income taxation generated a revenue surplus which, as the public choice model predicts, was increasingly used to expand the bureaucracy, both in government and in the universities themselves. Finally, the Dawkins revolution converted higher education into a total command economy administered from Canberra.

The vastly increased paperwork demands of a vastly expanded Commonwealth department generated multiple new layers of career bureaucracy in the universities — not only vice-chancellors, deputy vice-chancellors, pro-vice-chancellors, directors and co-ordinators, but also full-time deans, deputy deans and heads of department. At a university with which I am familiar the ratio of teaching academics to administrative staff sank to 0.6 to 1. In other words, there were substantially more full-time bureaucrats than teaching staff, a disturbing fact that several senior academics tried unsuccessfully to bring up for debate.114 Nearly all students now pay fees, building up large debts through the HECS system. Academic salaries in real relative terms are a little over one-third of their level in the 1960s.115 And when the university budget has to be cut, it is the teaching academics, not the administrators, who bear the weight of the retrenchments.

On the other hand, research in Australia and abroad shows that competitive federalism, by creating a competitive market for public goods, provides consumer-taxpayers with their preferred mix of public goods at the lowest tax price.116 Though the composition of the tax/service bundles may vary, the proportion of revenue that is appropriated for the purposes of the bureaucracy and politicians is less because no government is able to exact a surplus from its citizens.117 Competition, coupled with the right of exit, also makes it harder for states systematically to favour particular regions while imposing the costs on other regions.118 Overall, competition gives governments an incentive to improve their performance in all areas, including the law. Judicial appointments are more likely to be made on grounds of merit rather than political affiliations, because a court system that is seen to be unpredictable or biased is a factor in business decisions on where to establish plants or headquarters.119

The efficiency gains from competitive federalism are not significantly reduced by the smaller size of State governments. There are few economies of scale in government except in the areas of defence and foreign relations, nor are large organizations necessarily any better at dealing with complex problems than smaller ones.120 As Gordon Tullock points out, the Cray is the world’s most complex computer, but the Cray company is not a particularly large computer company. Further, he continues, many of the functions carried out by national governments are not complex, notably the distribution of health and social welfare payments, which is the largest single portion of their work. The actual provision of health services, for example, is quite complex, but that is performed by smaller organizations such as hospitals or medical practices. The part of the operation that is centralized is the simplest portion.121

Even in highly centralized governments, a great many decisions must be made at a low level.122 All Commonwealth departments of any size maintain offices in the State capitals where most of the core work is done, and which enjoy varying degrees of semi-autonomy.

The duplication issue. This leads to an issue that often arises in discussions of efficiency in a federal system: the question of duplication. This can be vertical (that is, overlap between federal and State government activities) or horizontal (duplication as among the States themselves). As to the vertical type, the fact that there is a Commonwealth department of health and a State department of the same name does not necessarily mean they are duplicating one another, any more than the State office of the Commonwealth department of social security is necessarily duplicating the work of its own head office in Canberra. They may be dealing with different aspects of the problem. The federal department of health may be wholly or partly unnecessary, in the sense that it is performing a task that would be better left to the forces of competition, but it is not necessarily duplicating a State function.

To the extent that there is actual duplication, it seems to stem in the main from the Commonwealth’s entry into areas in which it has no legislative power, such as education, as a result of pressure from special interest groups such as the teacher unions. The constitutional vehicle for this has been the making of Commonwealth grants which, under the High Court’s extremely wide interpretation of s.96, are subject to extensive conditions amounting to detailed, day-to-day regulation. The remedy lies in a more balanced reading of s.96, which, as its wording makes clear, was intended as a largely transitional measure of relatively minor importance. In the educational sphere, a proper interpretation of s.96 would allow the Commonwealth to play a useful role in, for example, interstate co-ordination, educational research and the development of comparable standards, at much lower cost than the authoritarian and counterproductive interference seen in recent years.

A common criticism based on vertical duplication is that, with two sets of politicians, State and Commonwealth, Australia is over-governed, and that it would be more efficient to dispense with the lower tier.

In 1996 Australia had 576 State parliamentarians.123 That is not a huge number when compared with the 378,700 people employed in government (not counting those engaged in education, health care or social welfare, or working for government corporations), or with the nation’s 878,800 managers and administrators. But it is unrealistic to suppose that abolishing the States would lead to a net saving of those 576 positions plus their support staffs.

Centralists always suggest replacing the six States with “regions”, somewhere between 20 and 37 in number.124 This structure would require the appointment of regional governors, prefects, sub-prefects, Gauleiter or what have you, together with support staff. France’s regions are administered by an elite corps préfectoral,a highly-paid class who live like diplomats in their own country, with official residences, servants and entertainment budgets. Sooner or later, as in France, our national government would be forced to create elected regional assemblies, between 20 and 37 in number. By then, any savings would long since have evaporated. As matters stand, the 38.3 per cent of GDP that Australia allocates to general government expenditure is lower than the United Kingdom’s 44.1 percent or France’s 52.0 per cent.125 Six sets of State parliamentarians thus look like quite an efficient arrangement.

A variant of the vertical duplication argument is the simple assertion that Australia’s population is just too small to support six State governments. Some comparisons may be helpful here. In 1788 the population of the thirteen American States was 3 million, significantly less than Australia’s population in 1901. By 1832 it had risen to 15 million,126 but probably did not match Australia’s current population of 18 million until about 1840. Switzerland, that land of supreme efficiency, has 5.5 million people for its 23 cantons. It is a more decentralized federation than Australia, with even some defence functions being performed by the cantons.

Horizontal duplication may to some extent be unavoidable because of the sheer size of the country. That aside, however, Professor Wolfgang Kasper of the University of New South Wales – ADFA answers the point :

“All competition requires a degree of duplication, but the reward is that the deadweight loss and the monopoly rents of the ‘government cartel’ disappear. New, productive ideas about public administration are generated. The [duplication] argument is no different from any defence of monopoly and cartels. Nor is it intellectually more respectable because administrators and not businessmen are involved in rigging the market …[D]uplication within rival State and local governments will serve the constructive purpose of enhancing the contribution of government to economic growth and citizen welfare”.127

In the days of the old Telecom government monopoly, the opponents of competition argued that if its monopoly were removed, call charges would rise and service would decline because of the costs of duplication. The opposite has happened, and Telstra today is scarcely recognizable as the same corporation as the surly monster of old.

10. A competitive edge for the nation

Often overlooked, even by advocates of economic federalism, is the value of competition among the States as a means of enhancing the international competitiveness of the nation as a whole. In other contexts this principle is quite a familiar one. It is, for example, the basis on which international sporting teams are selected. Out of the deliberately encouraged rivalry between local, regional and State teams emerges the squad that will represent Australia in the Olympics or other international event. No other means of identifying the best possible national team has ever been seriously suggested. Competitive federalism harnesses this principle, which Australia has used with unequalled success in the sporting field, to the goal of earning a better standard of living for all.

That this principle applies to the economic sphere can plainly be seen from the case of China, which emerged as a world economic power only after it became a de facto federation by devolving wide economic policy-making powers to the provinces.

A local example can be found in the Australian road transport industry. After the High Court’s interpretation of s.92 of the Constitution swept away most of the regulatory structure that had impeded its development, Australian trucking rapidly earned the nation the reputation of having the world’s most efficient system of long-distance road transport.128 It has been used as a case study and model in the deregulation of road transport throughout the world. Trucking in fact became one of our first multinational industries, with Australian companies making inroads in some of the world’s most competitive markets, including North America.

Facilitating the selection function. Professor Kasper argues that federations have a real advantage in discovering rules and devices that assist international competitiveness. He proposes four conditions for enabling competitive federalism to perform this selection role most effectively:

1. The principle of subsidiarity mentioned above, under which tasks should be administered centrally only when there are proven welfare gains from centralization, as when a diversity of rules leads to unnecessarily high transaction costs — for example, if there were different weights and measures in each State.

2. The “rule of origin”, which means that a product or service is automatically accepted throughout the country if it is deemed acceptable on health, safety and other grounds in the State in which it was produced. At present, Professor Kasper argues, we have excessive and unsystematic regulation because there is a cartel of regulators who are unchecked:

“Under a rule of origin, State and local governments that want to attract industry will compete with one another to develop the best possible set of regulations. This will put a competitive check on the regulators”.

A State that prescribed poor safety standards that hurt consumers would soon lose its attractiveness to industry, which would seek certification by a State with appropriate standards.

3. Assignment of tasks under the Constitution is clear and explicit. At present, Canberra has usurped tasks far beyond those granted to it in Chapter I, Part V of the Constitution in areas such as education and industry regulation. This, Professor Kasper argues, has created overlap and duplication that impose unnecessary compliance costs and lessen Australia’s international competitiveness.

4. Fiscal equivalence: each level of government should finance its assigned and chosen tasks with the funds it raises. The beneficiaries of a public service should as far as possible be identical with those who are asked to pay for it. This would eliminate inefficient compromises, “fiscal illusion”, free-riding and much political conflict. States would have an incentive to create their own, growing tax bases by pursuing far-sighted policies and competing for mobile resources. If the present vertical fiscal imbalance were eliminated, governments and the voters who elect them would have to live with the long-term consequences of their tax and development policies.129 A similar point was made by Lord Bryce, who added that this would strengthen the sense of responsibility and spirit of self-reliance of the people.130

A race to the bottom? Professor Kasper deals with the most likely criticisms of his proposal,131 but there is one objection which is sure to be pursued strongly and merits further attention. It is the proposition that the “rule of origin” would induce States to compete by lowering industry standards to the detriment of the public. This is the “race-to-the-bottom” argument, which has been used to justify, among other things, the uniform Corporations Law.

In answering this objection, one may begin by pointing out that the Commonwealth has the undoubted power under s.51(i) of the Constitution to set minimum standards of health, safety and integrity in interstate and overseas trade. The exercise of those powers can be a legitimate part of its role of setting the basic framework for the economic order.

A State that wished to prescribe more stringent standards would need to consider carefully whether the evidence genuinely justified that step. If it did, producers in that State might actually gain a competitive advantage from the legislation. For example, if South Australia were to ban the use of genetically-engineered soya beans in processed food, and research actually showed that the beans were bad for you, local processors could advertise interstate that their products were 100 per cent free of the offending vegetable and so reap extra sales among health-conscious consumers. If the ban were not empirically justified but stemmed from food-faddist paranoia, the government and the voters who elected it would have to accept the consequences in reduced economic activity and job opportunities.

Professor Richard Espstein evaluates the race-to-the-bottom argument specifically in relation to corporation laws and finds it to be flawed. He points out that the protection individual investors receive under a system of federalism derives from their ability to withhold their consent. If the rules facilitate the exploitation of shareholders, initial investors (including institutional investors with great sophistication) will demand at incorporation more favourable terms to compensate them for the added risks they are asked to assume. Noting that businesses announcing an intention to shift their state of incorporation to Delaware (the State that pioneered simplified incorporation laws) see significant advances in the value of their shares, he concludes that the exit right offers incentives for States to find the right mix between contractual freedom and State regulation. As regards creditors, he considers it likely to be only the rare situation in which incorporation in a particular State would benefit shareholders as a group but at the same time subject outside creditors (who otherwise benefit from the increased asset cushion) to greater risks than they would otherwise face:

“If most shareholders are risk averse, it is unlikely they will support, even by a simple majority vote, any reincorporation in another State that increases the volatility of their holdings, the scenario most likely to prejudice any creditors”.132

Other scholars who have examined the race-to-the-bottom thesis in environmental and commercial law have likewise concluded that it lacks empirical foundation.133

The truth about railway gauges. No discussion of governmental competition and efficiency in the Australian federation can overlook the old reproach that Australia’s mixture of railway gauges is a consequence of the federal system. As the main rail networks were completed decades before federation, presumably the argument is that if a unitary Constitution had been adopted in 1901 we would not have had to wait until now to have merely the mainland State capitals linked by standard gauge; or that, if a unitary system had been adopted earlier (much earlier), the differences would never have come about in the first place.

The argument does not withstand scrutiny. The United Kingdom too had a variety of gauges, the 7 foot broad gauge being particularly widespread in the densely-populated south. But most of the non-standard track was converted by the 1880s. In fourteen working days in 1872, 380 kilometres of double track, including pointwork in stations, were converted without stopping the traffic. The 690 kilometre main line from London to Penzance via Bristol was narrowed to standard gauge in a single weekend. The United States in 1861 had 20 different gauges, but all were standardized within two decades. In July, 1881, 3,000 workmen converted the entire 885 kilometres of the Illinois Central southern lines by 3:00pm on a single day.134

Obviously our federal structure cannot account for the fact that, over a century later, most of Australia’s non-standard rail networks are still unconverted. The answer, as Gary Sturgess has suggested, probably lies in the fact that Australia’s railways were from the outset government-owned.135 In the absence of the profit motive, the most powerful motivation in the world of economic affairs is the desire for the quiet life.136

Conclusion

All human institutions are imperfect and open to criticism. But for a framework of government that has created a new nation and given it external security, internal peace, stability, progress and prosperity throughout the most violent, turbulent century in human history,137 Australia’s federal Constitution has been subjected to an inordinate amount of negative comment. Reasons for this were suggested earlier, but the chief obstacle to balanced appraisal today is the failure of the main opinion communicators to consider the advantages of federalism.

The debate has focused exclusively on its disadvantages, and has generally taken the form of assertions repeated so often as to become accepted as facts. Minor inconveniences have been given an inflated importance by critics who, in Professor Galligan’s words, “did not appreciate the powerful liberal rationale that underpinned this ingenious system of government”138 and failed to consider the costs and disadvantages of an alternative system. Nor has it occurred to them that the “horse and buggy” constitutional model of 1901 might be more serviceable and environmentally friendly than the “Model T Ford” version that has dominated the constitutional highways since the 1920 Engineers’ Case.139

That the benefits outlined above are not being fully achieved at present results from the current imbalance between centralization and decentralization, uniformity and diversity, co-operation and competition. Lord Bryce’s “watertight compartments” have been punctured and the ship is listing towards centralized uniformity, denying the people the benefits of competitive federalism and bringing government cartelization, inefficiency and elitism.

Australian federalism can begin to realize its full potential if all three branches of Commonwealth government take into account the benefits of experimentation, diversity and multi-level democratic participation. They must recognize that competition and co-operation both have their place in a federation. The judiciary obviously has a crucial part to play here.

The United States Supreme Court, in a series of decisions over the last five years, has called a halt to sixty years of centralist jurisprudence, declaring that the federal division of powers is part of constitutional law, is there for a purpose and must be respected.140 In similar manner, the High Court could usefully revisit the extreme141interpretations of constitutional provisions such as s.51 (xxix) (external affairs)142 and s.90 (excise duties),143 that have crippled the working of the decentralized political structure called into being in 1901.

Voters should refuse to accept further centralization of authority unless the benefits of greater Commonwealth power can be shown to outweigh the costs. Nor need people be too awed by claims that centralization is “vital” for the resolution of some current “crisis”. Exaggerating a problem, or even engineering a crisis so as to create a clamour for something to be done, and then stepping forward with a prepared solution that further concentrates power and curtails freedom, is a time-honoured tactic of certain centralists.144

Some adjustments in thinking will be required under a true system of competitive and co-operative federalism. State governments will need to shoulder full responsibility for their own spheres of action and not seek to shunt the hard issues down the line to Canberra. In the general population, some individuals may at first be disconcerted by the wider range of choices available to them. It has happened before. When the old price cartels and monopolies were starting to break down under the Trade Practices Act 1967, there were some consumers who actually complained about the advent of discounting because prices were no longer uniform. Eventually they realized that by shopping around a little — that is, by taking responsibility for their own lives and choices — they could enjoy a significantly higher standard of living than before. The same process will take place when the current political cartel begins to crack.

Those who contrast the veneration with which Americans view their 1788 Constitution with the alleged apathy of Australians towards theirs overlook the fact that for the first hundred years of its life the United States Constitution was intensely unpopular in a way that the Commonwealth Constitution has never been during its own first century.145

Nevertheless, an awareness of the positive benefits of federalism will make the constitutional debate a more equal and fruitful one. This will mean recognizing that, in a properly working federation, government is more adaptable to the preferences of the people, more open to experiment and its rational evaluation, more resistant to shock and misadventure, and more stable. Its decentralized, participatory structure is a buttress of liberty and a counterweight to elitism. It fosters the traditionally Australian, but currently atrophying, qualities of responsibility and self-reliance. Through greater ease of monitoring and the action of competition, it makes government less of a burden on the people. It is desirable in a small country and indispensable in a large one. And if, as is often said, the pursuit of truth in freedom is the essence of civilization, this “liberating and positive form of organization” has a special contribution to make to the progress of humankind.

Speed up massacre trial, court urged

PhilstarPhilstar

Journalists carry mock coffins and pictures of massacred colleagues while marching to Mendiola in Manila yesterday to commemorate the third anniversary of the killing of 58 people, including 33 journalists in Maguindanao. <b>EDD GUMBAN                                                                                                                                                               </b>

MANILA, Philippines – Various groups called on the government to speed up the trial of the Maguindanao massacre case as protest rallies yesterday highlighted the third anniversary of the murders, considered the worst single incident of electoral violence in recent Philippine history and the single deadliest attack on the press ever.

This developed as President Aquino yesterday vowed to push for more judicial reforms and ensure that the trial of the Maguindanao massacre and other cases would be expedited.

“As the saying goes, ‘Justice delayed is justice denied,’ so our courts must work efficiently. We must have courts that are impartial and fair in the verdicts they hand down,” Aquino said.

“If the courts demonstrate impunity at the top, then the lowest regional trial courts will follow suit. This is why I have been so focused on reforming our justice system,” he said.

Aquino was keynote speaker at the 9th Media Nation Summit in Tagaytay City that coincided with the third anniversary of the Maguindanao massacre where journalists also fell victim to the carnage.

Related story: E-resource on Ampatuan murder trial launched

“In cases of media killings, for example, we in government are demanding the apprehension of suspects and the filing of charges that stick, resulting in justice for all involved,” Aquino said in his speech.

“In other cases of violence involving media, we have taken affirmative and just action. For instance, you may have heard of a governor who was suspended after assaulting a broadcaster on air. More than anything, the protection of the rights of all – journalists included – relies on the fair and impartial dispensation of justice,” he said.

Aquino ordered the one-year suspension of Northern Kalinga Gov. Jocel Baac after a video showed him bursting into the studio of dzRK radio and whacking a broadcaster on the head with a microphone.

Anchor Jerome Tabanganay said Baac apparently was irked by the station’s commentaries on illegal gambling and logging in the upland province.

Aquino warned in his order handed down over the weekend that similar action will be dealt with more severely.

In other news: PNoy assures justice for victims of media killings on anniv of Maguindanao massacre

The Philippines is tagged as one of the most dangerous countries in the world for journalists, highlighted by the killing of over 30 journalists in the Maguindanao massacre.

On Thursday, presidential spokesman Edwin Lacierda said Malacañang remained committed in ensuring that justice would be served to the massacre victims. 

At least 58 people were killed, including 32 members of the media on Nov. 23, 2009 when around a hundred gunmen stopped a convoy on its way to file the candidacy of now Maguindanao Gov. Esmael Mangudadatu.

The victims were systematically murdered and buried in shallow pits or dumped in grasslands near a remote highway in Sitio Masalay, Ampatuan town.

Groups across the nation espousing free expression and press organizations marked the third anniversary of the massacre yesterday calling for the speedy resolution of the case. Several sectors also lamented the slow pace of the trial.

Also related: Three years after, justice remains elusive to Maguindanao massacre victims

Many nations, including the United States, are calling on the Philippine government to improve the investigation and prosecution of cases of extra-judicial killing, according to US Ambassador Harry Thomas Jr.

Thomas issued the statement as he extended his government’s condolences to the families of the 58 victims as they observed the third anniversary of the brutal massacre in Maguindanao, according to Tina Malone, US embassy public affairs officer.

Thomas said the call for the Philippines to improve its efforts in resolving cases of extrajudicial killings was made by several nations during the UN Human Rights Commission’s Universal Periodic Review (UPR) of the Philippines.

Thomas also welcomed President Aquino’s pledge to bring those responsible for the crime to justice, end impunity for the perpetrators, and demonstrate to the world the Philippines’ commitment to upholding the rule of law and protecting human rights.

“We appreciate the efforts of the officials from the Philippine National Police (PNP), Department of Justice (DOJ), and courts working to bring closure to this case. We shall never forget the victims of that merciless act committed in Maguindanao on Nov. 23, 2009,” Thomas said.

Related story: Slow-paced trial makes moving on difficult for widow of Maguindanao massacre victim

The Canadian embassy in Manila said they are trusting that the trial of suspects in the Maguindanao massacre will be done in a timely and credible manner. 

“In remembering the victims, Canada understands that the massacre was not only a terrible act of violence but also an attack on the values shared by Canadians and Filipinos. Human rights, freedom of the press and freedom of expression are the cornerstones of our societies, and must be respected and protected,” the embassy said in a statement. 

Slow pace

Human rights groups said the slow pace of trial and the government’s failure to arrest nearly a hundred suspects raise grave concerns for the safety of witnesses and for obtaining justice for the victims.

“Canada recognizes the process to bring those responsible to justice continues, and trusts this will be done in a timely and credible manner. Moving forward, Canada is hopeful electoral violence in the Philippines will remain a thing of the past,” the embassy added.

UK Ambassador Stephen Lillie said a swift resolution and successful prosecution of those involved in the Maguindanao massacre would reinforce the UK and Philippines’ shared aspiration of upholding a democratic society. While nothing can be done to bring back the lives lost, bringing the perpetrators to justice will go some way to helping the victims’ families cope with their loss, Lillie said.

The UK condemned the brutal massacre in Maguindanao and called for urgent action to bring the perpetrators to justice, noting that effective action will be crucial in maintaining confidence in the Philippines’ commitment to protect human rights.

Even the communist rebels decried the slow pace of justice for the victims of the massacre.

In other news: UPLB coed’s slay suspect surrenders

National Democratic Front Philippines-Mindanao chapter spokesman Jorge Madlos said three years have passed and nothing has happened yet to the trial on the case. 

Media groups led by Center for Community Journalism and Development, Center for Media Freedom and Responsibility, Freedom Fund for Filipino Journalists, National Union of Journalists of the Philippines, Philippine Center for Investigative Journalism, Philippine Press Institute, and the University of the Philippines-College of Mass Communication led a rally at the Welcome Rotonda in Quezon City marking the third anniversary of the massacre.

The media groups also criticized the Aquino administration for failing to address the issues concerning the media.

“The families of the 58 victims of the Nov. 23, 2009 Ampatuan Massacre are starting to lose hope in the justice system, and the government has only itself to blame,” they said in a joint statement.

Other groups also held protest rallies in Cagayan de Oro City, in Cotabato City and Zamboanga City, calling on the government to speed up the trial of the case. – Pia Lee-Brago, Janvic Mateo, John Unson, Dino Balabo, Edith Regalado, Roel Pareño, Jigger Jerusalem, Sandy Araneta – By Aurea Calica (Philstar News Service, http://www.philstar.com)

Lynching Laurel (Reblog from josephonperspectives.wordpress.com)

 

Herman Tiu-Laurel: Anti foreign direct investment yet he is wearing Western business suit, speaking English, writing in English in his column, a partly Chinese. Certified hypocrite indeed.

Last Friday, after reading the article written by Herman Tiu-Laurel through The Daily Tribune titled “‘Opening-up’ RP“, in respond to Peter Wallace’s column titled “Constitutional change now” with a xenophobic rhetoric particular against the Australians, the nationality of Peter Wallace of saying that he should return to the land of ”bandits, rogues and garbage”.

I could not control myself but to respond his garbage, miseducated, and xenophobic editorial that was published not just in the internet through the website of The Daily Tribune but also in the conventional print circulation distributed nationwide wherein few could had read his editorial and I have to write his rebuttal in order not to be brainwashed or mislead by a certain Herman Tiu-Laurel.

He writes that our neighboring Asian countries have restrictions in foreign equity ownership in certain economic sectors, except except in sectors where locals have no competence, inclination or capital to venture in. I do agree on that however, he forgot that their restrictions in foreign equity ownership in certain economic sectors have been done through a simple legislation framework that would be easier for them to restrict or relax foreign equity ownership restrictions in certain economic sectors unlike here in the Philippines, wherein our foreign equity ownership restrictions have been stipulated in our 1987 constitution at all economic sectors practically (Article XII, Section 2, 10-11; Article XIV, Section 4; and Article XV, Section 11) or what we known as the 60/40 forced equity ownership sharing in favor of a Filipino individuals or corporations where foreign investors have to surrender their 60% of control of their own capital to a certain Filipino individual or corporation which is riskier compared of letting foreigners invest 100% from his/her own pocket and control what he invest in a particular business.

He forgot to realize that as of July 2012, the Philippines only got $900 million foreign direct investment inflows compared with $800 million in July 2011, a growth of 10.6% but still one of the laggard in Asean compared on what Singapore got in July 2012 of $27.4 billion, slightly 1.9% below compared with the same period last year but still one of the prime destination for foreign investments in Asean.

I will show you a differences between the Philippines and Singapore in terms of its openness on foreign investments according to the 2010 World Bank study, Investing Across Borders:

You see, the Philippines has more restrictions of foreign equity ownership because of the idiotic 60/40 forced equity sharing in favor of a Filipino individuals or corporations.

Singapore has the most relaxed foreign investment regimes according to the 2010 IAB study by the World Bank.

He writes that the country already has significant surplus in foreign exchange holdings relative to its foreign debt, and P1.8 trillion in savings from overseas Filipino workers, export and BPO sectors held in the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP) paying four percent to keep in its vaults. While I do agree that we have a significant surplus in Forex holding but he did not realize that the money is not meant to be spend for other expenses to our government like social, infrastructure, and many others but the bulks of Forex reserve by the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas will be used to cushion our foreign exchange relative with other world currencies from the fluctuations of global economy, therefore our foreign exchange holdings are for the protection of our currency. He says that we have P1.8 trillion savings from overseas Filipino workers but I tell you, Herman, what’s the use of that trillions of pesos of remittances from our OFWs only 15% is meant for investment that would have provide jobs for Filipinos at home while the other 85% is meant for consumption whether needy or conspicuous, you cannot grasp the spending attitudes of most OFWs who went abroad forcibly just to support their remaining families here in our country while causing other social problems like adultery, drug addiction, early pregnancy, and among others yet you are encouraging more Filipinos to go out of our country while not fixing our investment climate so that instead of Filipino workers going abroad, the foreign investors should be the one will come here in our country to provide jobs to millions of unemployed Filipinos, give technical expertise to the Filipino workers, give technological expertise to the Filipino entrepreneurs, and many others. The goal here in order to lure more investors is to give them a better environment so that they will invest here in our country instead of driving them out of our country like foreign equity ownership restrictions in the constitution.

He keeps saying that the money from the Forex reserves, our OFWs remittances, exports, and BPO revenues should be used for productive agriculture and manufacturing enterprises which would necessarily compete and substitute for goods imported today today — local dairy, shoes, clothes, steel, machinery and others. He did not realize that the money the government gained through taxation does not have enough capabilities and manpower on spending it in agriculture or manufacturing and instead, the government cannot fulfill those tasks compared with the private sector in running enterprises as the government had to rely on appropriations not on profit on targeting the market needs or allocating money for improving services. Without real foreign competition in the domestic market as a result of restrictive investment regime stipulated in our 1987 constitution, there is no motivation from the locally-owned enterprise to expand their market or improving their services to the consumers and their workers. His argument that we have no shortage of local capital is useless as long as the people does not have enough purchasing power to spend beyond their basic needs.

In order to have our economy more inclusive economic growth, let us encourage foreign capital, technology, and expertise to enter in our country without much restrictions and with proper regulations so that if there will be more competing companies for jobs in order for their businesses to operate, more unemployed Filipinos will be given an opportunity for employment at home instead abroad as more competing businesses for jobs tends to increase wages over time in order to maximize the labor supply and order for a company to maintain its workers from transferring to other competing companies. Higher wages over time means that there will be an increase of  purchasing power among the workers to spend for conspicuous necessities or for establishing a small enterprise to compete with existing enterprises for consumers and workers.

The power of free flow of capital, technology, and expertise are what Herman Tiu-Laurel cannot or maybe will not bother to grasp as he had to defend the interests of his bosses who are afraid of foreign competition that would diminish the profit margin of his bosses, therefore his financial survival while the Filipino people would be empowered with more competition in the economy whether the players are local or foreign.

Herman, you should eat your own words.

Philippine senator hints JFK a plagiarist

 

Asia News NetworkBy Cathy C. Yamsuan in Manila/Philippine Daily Inquirer | Asia News Network

  • Verdict: Guilty. -Senator Tito Sotto

    Verdict: Guilty. -Senator Tito Sotto

 
Manila (Philippine Daily Inquirer/ANN) – If I fall, you’re going down with me.

Senate Majority Leader Vicente Sotto III had to drag the dead in an effort to win an argument, calling attention to a news article insinuating that John F. Kennedy plagiarised an oft-quoted portion of his 1961 inaugural speech.

Sotto sent the Inquirer a text message bearing a link to the website http://www.dailymail.co.uk that when clicked would direct the reader to a story by Daniel Bates alleging that the slain US president lifted the quote “Ask not what the country can do for you, ask what you can do for your country” from his former headmaster in Choate, a boarding and day school in Wallingford, Connecticut.

The revelation is supposedly a detail from “Jack Kennedy: Elusive Hero,” the most recently released biography of probably the most popular chief executive in US history.

Related story: Sotto apologizes to Kennedy family

It is not difficult to guess what prompted Sotto to direct attention to the story.

The senator is accused of lifting quotes from a 1966 speech of the US president’s late brother, Sen. Robert Kennedy, translating these into Filipino and passing them off as his own in a speech delivered in September.

Sotto is facing an ethics complaint filed by a group of academicians who also accused the senator of lifting quotes from four US-based bloggers, twisting these to support his argument against the reproductive health (RH) bill and failing to properly credit them when he delivered three speeches in August and September against the measure.

At the Summit on Family Planning in the Business Sector on Thursday, former Foreign Secretary Roberto Romulo used the President Kennedy quote in his welcome remarks.

Quoted, not copied

“I think it would be appropriate to give you a quote; I assure you it’s a quote, I’m not plagiarising from John F. Kennedy who said, ‘Ask not what the country can do for you, ask what you can do for your country,” Romulo said.

He added, “I think this sums up what you can do for the country.”

Many interpreted Romulo’s effort to stress that he was quoting President Kennedy as an indirect attack against Sotto.

In other news: Kennedy daughter confirms plagiarism complaint vs Sotto

The website report said “‘Jack Kennedy: Elusive Hero,’ penned by US author Chris Matthews, claims the line originally came from George St. John, one of the president’s former headmasters at the Choate School in Connecticut.”

It added that Matthews “unearthed” notes written by St. John, “which suggest he had been aware of the ‘ask not’ line for many years.”

“The book also includes a reply to a questionnaire about JFK’s (Kennedy’s initials) time at the school, sent to his former classmates when he was president. One of the students wrote, ‘I boil every time I read or hear the Ask not’ exhortation as being original with Jack,” the report said.

“Time and time again we all heard [the headmaster] say that to the whole Choate family,” one source in the book was also quoted as saying.

Related story: Academics join bloggers in Sotto plagiarism

Kennedy’s 14-minute speech, delivered at his inauguration on Capitol Hill on Jan. 20, 1961, is often included in compilations of the best speeches ever delivered.

The website report predicted that Matthews’ “extraordinary revelation is sure to raise eyebrows among historians,” once it is released.

It added that Kennedy’s speech writer Theodoure C. Sorensen “has long been thought” as the source of the popular quote.

China urges ‘maximum restraint’ in Gaza

 

AFP NewsAFP News

Palestinians gather around a crater caused by an Israeli air strike on the al-Dallu family's home in Gaza City. China has called for "maximum restraint" by all parties, especially Israel, in the Gaza Strip conflict as the death toll from air strikes on the territory rose to 87

China on Monday called for “maximum restraint” by all parties, especially Israel, in the Gaza Strip conflict as the death toll from air strikes on the territory rose to 87.

The statement came as Israel pushed raids against Palestinian Hamas militants into a sixth day and geared up to expand operations with a ground offensive even as international efforts to broker a ceasefire gathered pace.

“We strongly urge relevant parties, in particular Israel, to exercise maximum restraint,” said Foreign Ministry spokeswoman Hua Chunying.

“China supports Arab countries’ just position on the Israeli-Arab issue.”

A UN Security Council member, China has voiced support for the Palestinian push for statehood and urged the international community to resolve the Israeli-Palestinian conflict, but not played an active role itself.

As with the neighbouring conflict in Syria, China generally opposes intervention in the internal affairs of other nations.

Senior officials from Hamas, which controls Gaza, have said that Egypt-mediated talks held on Sunday with Israel were “positive” but now focused on the need to guarantee the terms of any truce.

Analysts say Israel’s leadership appears satisfied with the success of Operation Pillar of Defence, which it launched in an effort to halt Palestinian rocket fire, and that could it be ready for a ceasefire.

The Israeli operation began with the targeted killing of Hamas military chief Ahmed Jaabari in an air strike last Wednesday.

The latest deaths came after a night of air strikes and sustained fire from navy ships.

Obama pushes change on historic Myanmar visit

 

AFP NewsBy Stephen Collinson | AFP News

US President Barack Obama hugs Myanmar opposition leader Aung San Suu Kyi following their meeting at her residence in Yangon, on November 19. Obama met Suu Kyi during a historic visit to Yangon aimed at encouraging political reforms

President Barack Obama urged Myanmar Monday to hasten its “remarkable” reforms on a historic visit during which he was feted by huge crowds and met Aung San Suu Kyi at the home where she was long locked up.

The trip, the first to Myanmar by a serving US president, came as the regime freed dozens more political prisoners to burnish its reform credentials and after the United States joined other Western powers in relaxing its sanctions.

After a red-carpet welcome for Air Force One, Obama met Myanmar’s reformist President Thein Sein and called on the former general to speed up the country’s march out of decades of iron-fisted military rule.

“Over the last year and a half, a dramatic transition has begun, as a dictatorship of five decades has loosened its grip,” Obama said afterwards in a major address at Yangon University during his whirlwind visit.

“This remarkable journey has just begun, and has much further to go,” he said. “The flickers of progress that we have seen must not be extinguished. They must be strengthened.”

Over the past few decades, “our two countries became strangers”, added Obama, who is on his foreign trip since winning re-election this month.

“But today, I can tell you that we always remained hopeful about the people of this country. About you. You gave us hope. And we bore witness to your courage.”

In once unthinkable scenes, Obama’s motorcade passed tens of thousands of flag-waving supporters — some chanting “America” — lining the streets of Yangon, the backdrop for several bloody crackdowns on pro-democracy uprisings.

Obama removed his shoes during a brief visit to Shwedagon Pagoda, a gold-plated spire encrusted with diamonds and rubies that is the spiritual centre of Burmese Buddhism.

He later stood side by side with democracy icon Aung San Suu Kyi at the lakeside villa where his fellow Nobel laureate languished for years under house arrest, as the presidential limousine sat parked outside.

Crowds could be heard chanting “Obama, freedom” in the streets nearby.

Suu Kyi for her part sounded a note of caution about the sweeping changes.

“The most difficult time in any transition is when we think that success is in sight,” she said. “We have to be very careful that we’re not lured by the mirage of success.”

The White House hopes Obama’s visit to Myanmar will strengthen Thein Sein’s reform drive, which saw Suu Kyi enter parliament after her rivals in the junta made way for a nominally civilian government.

The trip is seen as a political coup for Obama after his election victory and a major boost for Thein Sein, who has faced resistance from hardliners within his regime to the rapid political changes.

Obama has stressed his visit is not an “endorsement” of the regime but “an acknowledgement” of the reform process.

Some human rights groups said Obama should have waited longer to visit, arguing that he could have dangled the prospect of a trip as leverage to seek more progress such as the release of scores of remaining political prisoners.

Obama used his speech to urge an end to sectarian unrest in the western state of Rakhine, saying there was “no excuse for violence against innocent people”.

Two major outbreaks of violence since June between Muslims and ethnic Rakhine Buddhists in the state have left 180 people dead and more than 110,000 displaced.

Most of those who fled their homes were stateless Rohingya Muslims, who have faced decades of discrimination.

“For too long, the people of this state, including ethnic Rakhine, have faced crushing poverty and persecution. But there’s no excuse for violence against innocent people, and the Rohingya hold within themselves the same dignity as you do, and I do,” Obama said.

The setting for the speech was rich in symbolism. The university was the scene of past episodes of pro-democratic student unrest, including mass demonstrations in 1988 that ended in a bloody military crackdown.

Myanmar unveiled a series of new pledges on human rights ahead of Obama’s visit, vowing to review prisoner cases in line with “international standards” and open its jails to the Red Cross.

Activists said the regime also freed at least 44 political prisoners in an amnesty that coincided with his trip, but demanded more action.

“The government must release all political prisoners instead of using them as bargaining chips for visits like this (Obama’s),” Thailand-based activist Bo Kyi said, adding that more than 200 convicted dissidents remain in Myanmar’s jails.

DOH-NCR launches sign language module for health workers

 

GMA News OnlineGMA News Online

To help health workers communicate better with patients, especially those with hearing problems, the Department of Health (DOH) in Metro Manila has launched the first Filipino Sign Language (FSL) module.

DOH Metro Manila director Eduardo Janairo said health workers will be trained on “proper gestures and body movements” so they can communicate using sign language.

“We need to introduce FSL in our health care system and strengthen its use for the benefit of people who have difficulty hearing or speaking. Health workers will also benefit from using this module as it will enrich their knowledge, skills and awareness on the needs of people using FSL as their communication,” he said in a post on the DOH’s Facebook page.

Janairo said the module introduces the health worker to the basic signs they will need to communicate with deaf patients.

These include the alphabet, numbers, greetings, time, days, months and common questions asked in the emergency room, and using simple gestures.

The DOH cited figures from the 2000 Census on Persons with Disabilities (PWD) showing there are some 120,000 deaf people in the country.

It added the 2004 Philippine Registry on Persons with Disability showed 571 registered PWDs in Metro Manila with speech and hearing impairment.

 

Developing the FSL module were the Philippine Deaf Resource Center, University of the Philippines Philippine General Hospital, CAP College for the Deaf, De La Salle University – College of Saint Benilde and the Department of Education – National Capital Region.

“With this manual as a guide, we can address the health inequities in our health care system and ensure PWDs the administration of accurate health care treatment,” Janairo said.

He added the FSL module should pave the way for the adaption of FSL as a second medium of communication for the use of the Filipino deaf community.

Importance of training

The DOH said health workers should be educated with the basics of FSL so they can convey their messages and instructions on the services they are rendering to their deaf patients.

With the module, they can also understand the patient when he/she discloses information about his/her illness and providing an acceptable and appropriate treatment.

It will also minimize or prevent inaccuracy and errors in communication that can pose health risks and liabilities to health providers. — TJD, GMA News

Bacolod resort among world’s most ‘eco-friendly’

Yahoo! Southeast Asia Newsroom

 

By 

  • Nature's Village Resort in Bacolod is named one of the world's top 10 eco-friendly hotels (Photo from the website of Nature's Village)

    Nature’s Village Resort in Bacolod is named one of the world’s top 10 eco-friendly hotels (Photo from the website of Nature’s Village)

 

A resort in Visayas has proven that it is possible to offer world-class tourism and accomodation services while remaining environment-friendly.

Nature’s Village Resort in Bacolod has been named one of the world’s top ten eco-friendly hotels this year by international booking website Agoda.

The hotel fetched four out of five stars in the website’s ranking system, which is based on customer reviews.

It ranked highest among the 10 hotels in terms of food and dining and hotel cleanliness.

Related story: Metro Manila named among ‘destinations on the rise’

This is the second time Nature’s Village Resort gained international attention.

The hotel was also given the “ASEAN Green Star Hotel Award” in 2010, along with other high-end hotels in the Philippines.

“Hotels that once considered ‘eco-friendly’ to mean a small environmental footprint and conservation of resources are now taking things a step further…” Agoda chief executive Robert Rosenstein was quoted in reports as saying.

This, as he noted that hotels are also increasingly “cleaning up trash, investing in best-practices, actually improving the sustainability of the communities that surround them.”

In other news: Vigan City bags UN award for heritage site management

Bagging five stars in the Agoda list are Six Senses Ninh Van Bay in Vietnam, URBN hotel in China, Philea Resort and Spa in Malaysia, The Tongsai Bay in Thailand, and The Park New Delhi Hotel in India.

Alto Hotel on Bourke in Australia, and Casa Camper in Spain on the other hand got four stars each.

Rounding out the list of 10 are Borneo Highlands Resort in Malaysia and the Bangkok Tree House in Thailand, which have three stars each.

Also read: Luxury cruise ship now includes PH in travel route

Trimble urges Philippine Muslims to work for peace

AFP NewsAFP News – Sun, Nov 18, 2012

Nobel laureate Lord David Trimble, pictured here, urged Muslim rebels on Saturday to strive to overcome remaining hurdles to peace after they signed a landmark deal with the Philippine government

Nobel laureate Lord David Trimble urged Muslim rebels on Saturday to strive to overcome remaining hurdles to peace after they signed a landmark deal with the Philippine government.

Lord Trimble held up the example of the 1998 Belfast Good Friday agreement that ended the 30-year conflict in Northern Ireland as a template during a visit to the Moro Islamic Liberation Front camp in the southern Philippines.

“Our experience was it was difficult… to get an agreement. And when we did get an agreement, we found the implementation of the agreement challenging,” he told reporters accompanying him on the visit.

“And sometimes the challenges were not the ones we anticipated before.”

He said he discussed with MILF vice chairman for political affairs Ghazali Jaafar the potential roadblocks to the successful implementation of the deal the group signed with President Benigno Aquino’s government last month.

The 12,000-strong MILF agreed in the pact to give up its quest for an independent homeland in the south in return for significant power and wealth-sharing in a new autonomous region there to be known as Bangsamoro.

The pact aims to achieve a final peace by 2016, ending an insurgency that has claimed an estimated 150,000 lives since the 1970s.

“I am delighted with the framework agreement,” Trimble said.

There’ll still be a problem in the future, but I think the problem will be on a different order,” he added.

He urged the Muslim leadership to now shun violence and devote their efforts to improving the lives of the mainly Catholic nation’s large Islamic minority that the government says has been left impoverished by the MILF rebellion.

The two sides should work at creating opportunities as well as providing skills for the people whose lives had been disrupted by the 40-year conflict, to allow them to uplift their economic well-being, he added.

Trimble and Social Democratic and Labour Party leader John Hume were jointly awarded the Nobel Peace Prize in 1998 for their efforts at finding a peaceful solution to the conflict in Northern Ireland.

Southeast Asian nations feud over China

AFP NewsBy Martin Abbugao | AFP News

 

Fishing boats that have just returned from the disputed Scarborough shoal, are moored at Santa Cruz bay in May 2012. Southeast Asian leaders have clashed over how to handle tense maritime territorial disputes with China, overshadowing talks at a regional summit meant to strengthen trade and political ties

 

Southeast Asian leaders feuded on Monday over how to handle tense maritime territorial disputes with China, overshadowing talks at a regional summit meant to strengthen trade and political ties.

The leaders of the 10-member Association of Southeast Asian Nations had hoped to present a united front on the South China Sea row as they host Chinese Premier Wen Jiabao and US President Barack Obama for annual talks.

But that effort broke down just before Southeast Asian leaders were scheduled to meet Wen, amid divisions between Chinese ally Cambodia and the Philippines.

Cambodia, this year’s ASEAN chair, said on Sunday that Southeast Asian leaders had agreed not to “internationalise” the disputes and would confine negotiations to those between the bloc and China.

The apparent deal would have been a victory for China, which has long insisted that it should only negotiate directly with rival countries and that the Philippines should not seek support from the United States.

However Philippine President Benigno Aquino on Monday publicly rebuked Cambodian Prime Minister Hun Sen, telling his fellow leaders no such consensus had been reached and he would continue to speak out on the global stage.

“The Philippines… has the inherent right to defend its national interests when deemed necessary,” Philippine Foreign Secretary Albert del Rosario told reporters, quoting Aquino’s comments to his fellow leaders on Monday morning.

The feud echoed unprecedented infighting at an ASEAN foreign ministers’ meeting in Phnom Penh in July, which ended for the first time in the bloc’s 45-year history without a joint communique.

The Philippines and Vietnam had wanted the communique to make specific reference to their disputes with China. But Cambodia, the hosts of the talks and a close China ally, blocked the moves.

ASEAN members Vietnam, the Philippines, Malaysia and Brunei, as well as Taiwan, have claims to parts of the sea, which is home to some of the world’s most important shipping lanes and believed to be rich in fossil fuels.

But China insists it has sovereign rights to virtually all of the sea.

Tensions have risen steadily over the past two years, with the Philippines and Vietnam accusing China of increasingly aggressive diplomatic tactics to stake its claims.

Temperatures could rise again later Monday when Obama arrives in Phnom Penh to join the East Asia Summit, a two-day event also involving the leaders of Japan, South Korea, India, New Zealand and Australia.

Obama has previously angered China, and emboldened the Philippines, by calling for the rival claimants to agree on a legally binding code of conduct to govern their actions over the sea.

Analysts said he would likely repeat that call in Phnom Penh, as well as make comments highlighting the importance of freedom of navigation in the sea.

ASEAN officials had said they would push Wen during their talks on Monday to quickly start high-level, formal negotiations on a code of conduct.

But Chinese foreign ministry spokesman Qin Gang insisted that China wanted to continue with the current arrangement of lower-level talks on the issue. “We already have good discussions with ASEAN,” Qin said.

Even with the South China Sea row festering, countries involved in the East Asia Summit were expected to focus on ways to expand economic ties.

ASEAN nations are set to officially launch negotiations on Tuesday for an enormous free trade pact with China, Japan, India, South Korea, Australia and New Zealand.

And despite their own territorial rows, China, Japan and South Korea are likely to hold talks in Phnom Penh on Tuesday aimed at kick-starting three-way free trade negotiations, according to Qin.